Loading AI tools
Fixed-point theorem for set-valued functions From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
In mathematical analysis, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem for set-valued functions. It provides sufficient conditions for a set-valued function defined on a convex, compact subset of a Euclidean space to have a fixed point, i.e. a point which is mapped to a set containing it. The Kakutani fixed point theorem is a generalization of the Brouwer fixed point theorem. The Brouwer fixed point theorem is a fundamental result in topology which proves the existence of fixed points for continuous functions defined on compact, convex subsets of Euclidean spaces. Kakutani's theorem extends this to set-valued functions.
The theorem was developed by Shizuo Kakutani in 1941,[1] and was used by John Nash in his description of Nash equilibria.[2] It has subsequently found widespread application in game theory and economics.[3]
Kakutani's theorem states:[4]
The function: , shown on the figure at the right, satisfies all Kakutani's conditions, and indeed it has many fixed points: any point on the 45° line (dotted line in red) which intersects the graph of the function (shaded in grey) is a fixed point, so in fact there is an infinity of fixed points in this particular case. For example, x = 0.72 (dashed line in blue) is a fixed point since 0.72 ∈ [1 − 0.72/2, 1 − 0.72/4].
The function:
satisfies all Kakutani's conditions, and indeed it has a fixed point: x = 0.5 is a fixed point, since x is contained in the interval [0,1].
The requirement that φ(x) be convex for all x is essential for the theorem to hold.
Consider the following function defined on [0,1]:
The function has no fixed point. Though it satisfies all other requirements of Kakutani's theorem, its value fails to be convex at x = 0.5.
Consider the following function defined on [0,1]:
The function has no fixed point. Though it satisfies all other requirements of Kakutani's theorem, its graph is not closed; for example, consider the sequences xn = 0.5 - 1/n, yn = 3/4.
Some sources, including Kakutani's original paper, use the concept of upper hemicontinuity while stating the theorem:
This statement of Kakutani's theorem is completely equivalent to the statement given at the beginning of this article.
We can show this by using the closed graph theorem for set-valued functions,[5] which says that for a compact Hausdorff range space Y, a set-valued function φ: X→2Y has a closed graph if and only if it is upper hemicontinuous and φ(x) is a closed set for all x. Since all Euclidean spaces are Hausdorff (being metric spaces) and φ is required to be closed-valued in the alternative statement of the Kakutani theorem, the Closed Graph Theorem implies that the two statements are equivalent.
The Kakutani fixed point theorem can be used to prove the minimax theorem in the theory of zero-sum games. This application was specifically discussed by Kakutani's original paper.[1]
Mathematician John Nash used the Kakutani fixed point theorem to prove a major result in game theory.[2] Stated informally, the theorem implies the existence of a Nash equilibrium in every finite game with mixed strategies for any finite number of players. This work later earned him a Nobel Prize in Economics. In this case:
In general equilibrium theory in economics, Kakutani's theorem has been used to prove the existence of set of prices which simultaneously equate supply with demand in all markets of an economy.[6] The existence of such prices had been an open question in economics going back to at least Walras. The first proof of this result was constructed by Lionel McKenzie.[7]
In this case:
Kakutani's fixed-point theorem is used in proving the existence of cake allocations that are both envy-free and Pareto efficient. This result is known as Weller's theorem.
Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a special case of Kakutani fixed-point theorem. Conversely, Kakutani fixed-point theorem is an immediate generalization via the approximate selection theorem:[8]
By the approximate selection theorem, there exists a sequence of continuous such that . By Brouwer fixed-point theorem, there exists a sequence such that , so .
Since is compact, we can take a convergent subsequence . Then since it is a closed set.
The proof of Kakutani's theorem is simplest for set-valued functions defined over closed intervals of the real line. Moreover, the proof of this case is instructive since its general strategy can be carried over to the higher-dimensional case as well.
Let φ: [0,1]→2[0,1] be a set-valued function on the closed interval [0,1] which satisfies the conditions of Kakutani's fixed-point theorem.
Let (ai, bi, pi, qi) for i = 0, 1, … be a sequence with the following properties:
1. | 1 ≥ bi > ai ≥ 0 | 2. | (bi − ai) ≤ 2−i |
3. | pi ∈ φ(ai) | 4. | qi ∈ φ(bi) |
5. | pi ≥ ai | 6. | qi ≤ bi |
Thus, the closed intervals [ai, bi] form a sequence of subintervals of [0,1]. Condition (2) tells us that these subintervals continue to become smaller while condition (3)–(6) tell us that the function φ shifts the left end of each subinterval to its right and shifts the right end of each subinterval to its left.
Such a sequence can be constructed as follows. Let a0 = 0 and b0 = 1. Let p0 be any point in φ(0) and q0 be any point in φ(1). Then, conditions (1)–(4) are immediately fulfilled. Moreover, since p0 ∈ φ(0) ⊂ [0,1], it must be the case that p0 ≥ 0 and hence condition (5) is fulfilled. Similarly condition (6) is fulfilled by q0.
Now suppose we have chosen ak, bk, pk and qk satisfying (1)–(6). Let,
Then m ∈ [0,1] because [0,1] is convex.
If there is a r ∈ φ(m) such that r ≥ m, then we take,
Otherwise, since φ(m) is non-empty, there must be a s ∈ φ(m) such that s ≤ m. In this case let,
It can be verified that ak+1, bk+1, pk+1 and qk+1 satisfy conditions (1)–(6).
We have a pair of sequences of intervals, and we would like to show them to converge to a limiting point with the Bolzano-Weierstrass theorem. To do so, we construe these two interval sequences as a single sequence of points, (an, pn, bn, qn). This lies in the cartesian product [0,1]×[0,1]×[0,1]×[0,1], which is a compact set by Tychonoff's theorem. Since our sequence (an, pn, bn, qn) lies in a compact set, it must have a convergent subsequence by Bolzano-Weierstrass. Let's fix attention on such a subsequence and let its limit be (a*, p*,b*,q*). Since the graph of φ is closed it must be the case that p* ∈ φ(a*) and q* ∈ φ(b*). Moreover, by condition (5), p* ≥ a* and by condition (6), q* ≤ b*.
But since (bi − ai) ≤ 2−i by condition (2),
So, b* equals a*. Let x = b* = a*.
Then we have the situation that
If p* = q* then p* = x = q*. Since p* ∈ φ(x), x is a fixed point of φ.
Otherwise, we can write the following. Recall that we can parameterize a line between two points a and b by (1-t)a + tb. Using our finding above that q<x<p, we can create such a line between p and q as a function of x (notice the fractions below are on the unit interval). By a convenient writing of x, and since φ(x) is convex and
it once again follows that x must belong to φ(x) since p* and q* do and hence x is a fixed point of φ.
In dimensions greater one, n-simplices are the simplest objects on which Kakutani's theorem can be proved. Informally, a n-simplex is the higher-dimensional version of a triangle. Proving Kakutani's theorem for set-valued function defined on a simplex is not essentially different from proving it for intervals. The additional complexity in the higher-dimensional case exists in the first step of chopping up the domain into finer subpieces:
Once these changes have been made to the first step, the second and third steps of finding a limiting point and proving that it is a fixed point are almost unchanged from the one-dimensional case.
Kakutani's theorem for n-simplices can be used to prove the theorem for an arbitrary compact, convex S. Once again we employ the same technique of creating increasingly finer subdivisions. But instead of triangles with straight edges as in the case of n-simplices, we now use triangles with curved edges. In formal terms, we find a simplex which covers S and then move the problem from S to the simplex by using a deformation retract. Then we can apply the already established result for n-simplices.
Kakutani's fixed-point theorem was extended to infinite-dimensional locally convex topological vector spaces by Irving Glicksberg[9] and Ky Fan.[10] To state the theorem in this case, we need a few more definitions:
Then the Kakutani–Glicksberg–Fan theorem can be stated as:[11]
The corresponding result for single-valued functions is the Tychonoff fixed-point theorem.
There is another version that the statement of the theorem becomes the same as that in the Euclidean case:[5]
In his game theory textbook,[12] Ken Binmore recalls that Kakutani once asked him at a conference why so many economists had attended his talk. When Binmore told him that it was probably because of the Kakutani fixed point theorem, Kakutani was puzzled and replied, "What is the Kakutani fixed point theorem?"
Seamless Wikipedia browsing. On steroids.
Every time you click a link to Wikipedia, Wiktionary or Wikiquote in your browser's search results, it will show the modern Wikiwand interface.
Wikiwand extension is a five stars, simple, with minimum permission required to keep your browsing private, safe and transparent.